Laissez-faire economic policy was largely influenced by which economist?

This article traces economists’s attitudes towards government intervention since the term ‘laissez-faire’ was first used in late 17th- or early 18th-century France. Understanding of the term has changed significantly since then. Adam Smith, popularly associated with laissez-faire, had a much more nuanced and pragmatic view of the role of the state, as did many of the classical economists and their neoclassical successors. Dissatisfaction with certain aspects of industrial capitalism led to a more interventionist stance during the 20th century, though the second half of the century saw something of a reversion towards the classical approach.

Keywords

  • Banking School
  • Bastiat, C. F.
  • Behavioural economics
  • Boisguilbert, P.
  • Bright, J.
  • Cairnes, J. E.
  • Cambridge School
  • Capitalism
  • Chalmers, T.
  • Chicago School
  • Cobden, R.
  • Consumer surplus
  • Corporatism
  • Cowles Commission
  • Currency competition
  • Currency school
  • Division of labour
  • Economic freedom
  • Efficient allocation
  • Free banking
  • Gold standard
  • Government failure
  • Great depression
  • Hayek, F. A. von
  • Hobson, J. A.
  • Information, economic of
  • Institutionalism
  • Keynes, J. M.
  • Keynesianism
  • Laissez-faire
  • Lange, O. R.
  • List, F.
  • Manchester school
  • Marginal revolution
  • Market failure
  • Market socialism
  • Markets
  • Marshall, A.
  • McCulloch, J. R.
  • Mercantilism
  • Mill, J. S.
  • Minimum wages
  • Mises, L. E. von
  • Mont Pèlerin Society
  • Natural liberty
  • New classical macroeconomics
  • New Deal
  • North, D.
  • Optimal resource allocation
  • Planning
  • Public choice
  • Rational behaviour
  • Rational choice
  • Ricardo, D.
  • Role of government
  • Samuelson, P. A.
  • Sidgwick, H.
  • Smith, A.
  • Socialist calculation debate
  • Underconsumptionism
  • Utilitarianism
  • Viner, J.
  • Walras, L.

JEL Classifications

  • B1

This chapter was originally published in The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd edition, 2008. Edited by Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume

This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.

Bibliography

  • Balisciano, M.L. 1998. Hope for America: American notions of economic planning between pluralism and neoclassicism. History of Political Economy 30(Suppl): 153–78.

    CrossRef  Google Scholar 

  • Barber, W.J. 1985. From new era to new deal: Herbert Hoover, the economists, and American economic policy, 1921–1933. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    CrossRef  Google Scholar 

  • Barber, W.J. 1996. Designs within disorder: Franklin D. Roosevelt, the economists, and the shaping of American economic policy, 1933–1945. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    CrossRef  Google Scholar 

  • Cairnes, J.E. 1870. Political economy and laissez-faire. In Essays on political economy. London: Macmillan, 1873.

    Google Scholar 

  • Castelot, E. 1987. Laissez-faire, laissez-passer: History of the maxim. In The New Palgrave: A dictionary of economics, vol. 3, ed. J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, and P. Newman. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Faccarello, G. 2000. Foundations of laissez-faire: The economics of Pierre de Biosguilbert. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M., and R. Friedman. 1979. Free to choose. New York: Harcourt Brace.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gamble, A. 2006. Hayek on knowledge, economics and society. In The Cambridge companion to Hayek, ed. E. Feser. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gash, N. 1989. Review of Hilton 1988. English Historical Review 104: 136–40.

    CrossRef  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F.A. 1937. Economics and knowledge. Economica N.S. 4(13): 33–54.

    CrossRef  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F.A. 1944. The road to Serfdom. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F.A. 1999. Good money. In The collected works of F.A. Hayek, ed. S. Kresge. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilton, B. 1988. The age of atonement: The influence of evangelicalism on social and economic thought, 1785–1865. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hutchison, T.W. 1953. A review of economic doctrines, 1870–1929. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hutchison, T.W. 1978. On revolutions and progress in economic knowledge. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J.M. 1923. A tract on monetary reform. In The collected works of John Maynard Keynes, vol. 4. London: Macmillan, 1971.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J.M. 1926. The end of laissez faire. In Essays in persuasion. In the collected writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. 9. London: Macmillan, 1972.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J.M. 1936. The general theory of employment, interest and money. In The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. 7. London: Macmillan, 1973.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laidler, D.W. 1999. Fabricating the Keynesian revolution: Studies of the inter-war literature on money, the cycle, and unemployment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • List, F. 1856. The national system of political economy. New York: Kelley, 1966.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maloney, J. 2005. The political economy of Robert Lowe. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    CrossRef  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. 1890. The principles of economics, 8th ed. London: Macmillan, 1920.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mill, J.S. 1848. Principles of political economy, with some of their applications to social philosophy. In The collected works of John Stuart Mill, vol. 2–3, ed. J.M. Robson. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1965.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mill, J.S. 1859. On liberty. New York: Classics of Liberty Library, 1992.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mill, J.S. 1861. Considerations on representative government. In The collected works of John Stuart Mill: Essays on politics and society, vol. 19, ed. J.M. Robson. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1977.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mill, J.S. 1862. Centralisation. In The collected works of John Stuart Mill: Essays on politics and society, vol. 19, ed. J.M. Robson. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1977.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Mises, L. 1912. The theory of money and credit. Trans. H.E. Bateson. Indianapolis: Liberty Classics, 1980.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. 1691. Discourses upon trade. London: Thomas Basset.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Brien, D.P. 2004. The classical economists revisited. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oncken, A. 1886. Die Maxime Laissez Faire et Laissez Passer. Bern: Wyss.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A.C. 1912. Wealth and welfare. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A.C. 1920. The economics of welfare. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robbins, L.C. 1952. The theory of economic policy in English classical political economy. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothschild, E. 2001. Economic sentiments: Adam Smith, Condorcet and the enlightenment. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuels, W.J. 1966. The classical theory of economic policy. Cleveland: World.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. 1955. Economics, 3rd ed. New York: McGraw Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sidgwick, H. 1904. Principles of political economy. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sidgwick, H. 1907. The methods of ethics, 7th ed. London: Macmillan. Reprinted Indianapolis: Hackett, 1981.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. 1759. The theory of moral sentiments. In The works and correspondence of Adam Smith, vol. 1, ed. D.D. Raphael and A.L. Macfie. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1759.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. 1776. An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. In The works and correspondence of Adam Smith, vol. 2, ed. R.H. Campbell, A. Skinner, and W.B. Todd. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. 1978. Lectures on jurisprudence. In The works and correspondence of Adam Smith, vol. 5, ed. R.L. Meek, P.G. Stein, and D.D. Raphael. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1978.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viner, J. 1960. An intellectual history of laissez faire. Journal of Law and Economics 3: 49–69.

    CrossRef  Google Scholar 

  • Walras, L. 1954. Elements of pure economics: Or the theory of social wealth. Trans. W. Jaffe. Philadelphia: Orion.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

  1. http://link.springer.com/referencework/10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5

    Roger E. Backhouse & Steven G. Medema

Authors

  1. Roger E. Backhouse

    View author publications

    You can also search for this author in PubMed Google Scholar

  2. Steven G. Medema

    View author publications

    You can also search for this author in PubMed Google Scholar

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

© 2008 The Author(s)

About this entry

Cite this entry

Backhouse, R.E., Medema, S.G. (2008). Laissez-faire, Economists and. In: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_2206-1

Which economists use the term laissez

In a similar vein, Adam Smith viewed the economy as a natural system and the market as an organic part of that system. Smith saw laissez-faire as a moral program and the market its instrument to ensure men the rights of natural law. By extension, free markets become a reflection of the natural system of liberty.

Who were the main laissez

Laissez-faire was popularized by the economists/philosophers John Stuart Mill and Adam Smith in the 1800s. By the turn of the century, it was the dominant economic practice.